Online Learning Portal
Editorial Plus
26 May, 2020
10 Min Read
By, C.P. Chandrasekhar is former Professor at the Centre for Economic Studies and Planning, Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi
Introduction
5 Tranches
1. Tranche 1: Business including MSMEs (May 13, 2020)
2. Tranche 2: Poor, including migrants and farmers (May 14, 2020)
3. Tranche 3: Agriculture (May 15, 2020)
4. Tranche 4: New horizons of growth (May 16, 2020)
5. Tranche 5: Government reforms and enablers (May 17, 2020)
The fourth ‘l’
Prime Minister in his speech calling for a “self-reliant India” identified, besides land, labour and laws, “liquidity” as among the areas of focus of the package.
Liquidity refers to ease of access to cash — a liquid asset is one that can be easily sold for or replaced with cash, and a liquid firm or agent is a holder of cash, a line providing access to cash, or assets that can be easily and quickly converted to cash without significant loss of value.
|
In periods of crisis, individuals, small businesses, firms, financial institutions and even governments tend to experience a liquidity crunch.
Relaxing that crunch is a focus of the government’s crisis-response package.
Focus on NBFCs
# The main intermediaries being enlisted for the task of transmitting liquidity are the banks, with NBFCs constituting a second tier.
# Among the first steps taken by the RBI was the launch of special and ‘targeted’ long term repo operations (TLTROs), which allowed banks to access liquidity at the repo rate to lend to specified clients.
# One round of such operations, which was relatively more successful, called for investment of the cheaper capital in higher quality investment grade corporate bonds, commercial paper, and non-convertible debentures.
# That funding allowed big business, varying from Reliance and L&T to financial major HDFC, to access cheap capital to substitute for past high-cost debt or finance ongoing projects. There is little evidence that this is triggering new investment decisions.
# The second round was geared to saving NBFCs, whose balance sheets were under severe stress even before the COVID-19 strike, because they were finding it difficult to roll over the short-term debt they had incurred to finance longer term projects, including lending to small and medium businesses, housing and real estate.
# Banks were wary about lending to these NBFCs, because of fears that their clients could default in amounts that would bring the viability of these institutions into question.
# Those fears were confirmed when Franklin Templeton announced that it was shutting down six of its funds, setting off redemption requests across the NBFC sector, as investors rushed to take back their money, at a time when the ability of these institutions to mobilise funds to meet these demands had been impaired.
# Not surprisingly, banks were unwilling to respond when liquidity was infused to target lending to the NBFCs.
# The package identified more intermediaries (such as SIDBI, NABARD, NHB) that could refinance lending by the banks to different sections, with targeted lending amounts providing figures to fatten the “stimulus”.
# To persuade the banks and other intermediaries to take up these offers when the clients they must lend to (micro, small and medium enterprises, street vendors, marginal farmers, etc.) are themselves stressed, in some instances the government offered them partial or full credit guarantees in case their clients defaulted.
# The government also sought to persuade the RBI to lend directly to NBFCs against their paper.
# These measures, which are only marginally effective even in the best of times, will not work during this crisis.
# Consider a bank or NBFC lending to small business. With economic activity either at a complete stop or at a fraction of the normal, those who can access credit would either not borrow or only do so to protect themselves and not use the funds either to pay their workers or buy and stock inputs.
# Faced with sluggish demand, firms are unlikely to meet past and current payments commitments and help the revival effort, just because they have access to credit.
# This would mean that credit flow would actually not revive. This danger is even greater because the government has been measly with its guarantees, not wanting to accumulate even contingent liabilities that do not immediately affect the fiscal deficit.
On disposable income
# Another component of the “liquidity” push is the measures that temporarily increase the disposable income of different sections.
# Advance access to savings like provident fund contributions, lower tax deduction at source, reduced provident fund contributions and moratoriums on debt service payments for a few months, are expected to provide access to cash inflows and reduce cash outflows, to induce agents to meet overdue payments or just spend to enhance the incomes of others.
# Overall, the “transmission” of the supply side push from these monetary policy initiatives for relief and revival is bound to be weak. Given the circumstances, the liquidity push, even if partially successful, would only culminate in eventual default, as borrowers use the debt to just stay afloat in the absence of new revenues.
Think new transfers
What is needed now is government support in the form of new and additional transfers to people in cash and kind, and measures such as wage subsidies, equity support and spending on employment programmes.
That, as many have acknowledged, would require debt financed spending by the government, with borrowing at low interest rates from the central bank or a “monetisation” of the deficit.
Source: TH
Our Popular Courses
Module wise Prelims Batches
Mains Batches
Test Series